Come to class this week. We’re reading from leading economists
of the early 20th century who were avowed eugenicists.
This meant they
believed that the racial superiority of
whites was threatened by immigration and welfare policies that set up conditions for "dysgenic competition" between the races, with the darker groups snuffing out the supposed superiority of whites.
These economists strongly opposed immigration because this “race amalgamation” would dilute the “white stock.”
These economists strongly opposed immigration because this “race amalgamation” would dilute the “white stock.”
I share excerpts and welcome comments:
“Fear
and dislike of immigrants certainly were not new in the Progressive Era. But
leading professional economists were among the first to provide scientific respectability
for immigration restriction on racial grounds.
They justified race based immigration restriction as a remedy for ‘race suicide,’” a Progressive Era term for the process by which racially superior stock (“natives”) is outbred by a more prolific, but racially inferior stock (immigrants).
They justified race based immigration restriction as a remedy for ‘race suicide,’” a Progressive Era term for the process by which racially superior stock (“natives”) is outbred by a more prolific, but racially inferior stock (immigrants).
The
term “race suicide” is often attributed to Edward A. Ross (1901a, p. 88), who
believed that ‘the higher race quietly and unmurmuringly eliminates itself
rather than endure individually the bitter competition it has failed to ward
off by collective action.’”
By
1912, Simon Patten (p. 64), the reformist Wharton School economist who served
as AEA president in 1908, could say, “[T]he cry of race suicide has replaced the
old fear of overpopulation.”
In explaining why those of inferior stock were more prolific, early
Progressive Era economists emphasized how economic life under industrial
capitalism was increasingly dysgenic, that is, it tended to promote the survival of the unfit.
Patten,
for example, argued (as quoted in D. Ross, 1991, p. 197) that “every
improvement . . . increases the amount of the deficiencies which the
laboring classes may possess without their being thereby overcome in the struggle
for subsistence that the survival of the ignorant brings upon society.”
In
response, Patten ultimately argued for the state taking over the task of
selecting
the fittest—eugenics. “Social progress is a higher law than equality,” Patten
(1899, pp. 302–303) volunteered, and the only way to progress was the “eradication
of the vicious and inefficient.”
…
Practical
implications: Oppose any social welfare program that helped the poor on grounds
that compassion would help the poor survive … and “outbreed” successful people.
…
We will explore
whether there are echoes today from the past, including this example:
Walker (1899, p. 424) proposed that native Americans would not
compete with immigrants from the “low-wage races.” “The American shrank from
the industrial competition thrust upon him,” Walker argued. “He was unwilling
himself to engage with the lowest kind of day labor with these new elements of
the population; he was even more unwilling to brings sons and daughters into
the world to enter that competition.” Walker (1896, p. 828) characterized the
new elements of the population—“ peasants” from “southern Italy, Hungary,
Austria, and Russia”—as “beaten men from beaten races; representing the worst failures in the
struggle for existence.
Centuries
are against them, as centuries were on the side of those who formerly came to
us.” Walker (1899, p. 447) predicted that, without racial immigration restriction,
“every foul and stagnant pool of population in Europe, [in] which no breath of
intellectual life has stirred for ages . . . [will] be decanted upon our shores.”
Source: Thomas C. Leonard, Eugenics and Economics in the Progressive
Era (2005)
No comments:
Post a Comment