Friday, December 13, 2019

Farewell, Britannia


Image result for farewell britannia
Boris Johnson’s smashing success is a feel-good moment for nativists.
But they are all on the wrong side of history. Here is an excerpt from my forthcoming study on three empires that, at times, cutoff immigration and trade to their great detriment—Rome, Britain, and the U.S.:
Naturalization Laws and the Rise of the British Empire: From an early time, English law protected workers from foreigners.[1] But these policies isolated and slowed the English economy. In time, England allowed limited immigration to develop its business climate. Three waves of foreigners were admitted: Flemings in the fourteenth century, Dutch and Walloons in the sixteenth century, and French in the seventeenth century.[2] Over this long span, English governments regarded these foreigners as religious refugees and economic assets.[3] Beginning in 1331, Edward III promoted immigration of skilled craftsmen with letters of protection.[4] Weavers from Flanders were allowed entry to work.[5] Edward III cultivated industry and training by admitting skilled aliens.[6]
Within a short time, the Black Death created an immense labor shortage. The Ordinance of Labourers of 1349 reacted to wage inflation by capping wages across many trades and occupations.[7] A year later, citizenship was broadened in “A Statute for Those That Be Born Beyond the Sea.”[8] The law provided that inheritance rights for the “children of the kings of England, in whatsoever parts they be born, in England or elsewhere, be able ought to bear the inheritance after the death of their ancestors.”[9] Timing of the law suggests a national imperative to increase the labor pool by extending citizenship to English emigres.
Until the early sixteenth century, England remained in a trading rut, a small satellite in the orbit of Italy, the Mediterranean, Low Countries, and Germany.[10] The Hanseatic League was England’s primary trade partner in the 1400s: together, they granted favorable trading privileges in wool to Germanic guilds but disadvantaged English producers and merchants.[11] England’s primary export until 1565 was cloth— a finished commodity that required imported raw materials and dyes.[12] Not only did England import most products essential to its economy: It imported also Europe’s technical skills.[13]
As foreigners arrived in larger numbers during the early sixteenth century, this influx brought labor competition.[14] Native resentments exploded on Evil May Day 1517, a day of rioting against foreigners.[15] But the trade between foreign businesses and English artisans was so vital to the treasury that the king meted out cruel punishment against the nativists.[16] Thirteen young rioters were hanged; more than 400 others bound in ropes awaiting their fate at the gallows before they received a last-minute pardon.[17]
The population of foreign artisans swelled, constituting about one-third of Londoners.[18] Skilled labor in this period mostly came from foreigners, including tradesmen who worked for the royal household.[19] Their presence inflamed British subjects.[20] In consequence, the Aliens Act of 1540 restricted the rights of these workers.[21] Parliament reflected native concern that aliens “did eate the Englishmen out of trade, and that they entertained no Apprentizes, but of their own Nation.”[22] Before long, however, England adopted permissive immigration laws. During Elizabeth I’s reign, naturalization laws thrust England to the forefront as a continental trading partner. Foreigner artisans who mastered new drapery technologies provided a way for England to grow exports by adding new value to domestic materials.[23]



[1]   Daniel Thompson, The Weavers’ Craft 19 (1903) (the twenty-second law of the “Leges Burgorum,” written during the reign of David I (1124-1153), prohibited anyone but a burgess from making cloth or dyeing it).
[2]   Ephraim Lipson, The Economic History of England 60 (1937).
[3]   Id.
[4]   Lien Bich Luu, Immigrants and the Industries of London, 1500–1700 53-55 (2017) (Edward III promoted industrial development in his letters of protection to Flemish weavers, encouraging them to come and develop the cloth industry in England).
[5]   Also see Bart Lambert & Milan Pajic, Drapery in Exile: Edward III, Colchester and the Flemings, 1351–1367, 99 Hist. 338 (Dec. 2014) (as a result of Edward III granting Flemish textile workers letters of protection, skilled artisans helped Colchester become an international center of textile production. These letters were similar to modern actions by legislatures to grant a private form of naturalization.
[6]   Luu, supra note 176, at 54:
The king to all his bailiffs … to whom … greeting. Know you that since John Kempe of Flanders, weaver of woollen cloths, will come to stay within our realm of England to exercise his mystery here, and to instruct and teach those wishing to learn therein, and will bring certain men, servants and apprentices of that mystery, we have taken John and his aforesaid men, servants and apprentices, and their goods and chattels into our special protection of defence.
[7]   Braid, supra note 169, at 23-24.
[8]   25 Edw. III Stat. 2 (1350).
[9]   Id.
[10]   Luu, supra note 176, at 1.
[11]   Frederik Pedersen, Trade and Politics in the Medieval Baltic: English Merchants and England’s Relations to the Hanseatic League 1370-1437, in Public Power in Europe: Studies in Historical Transformations 161 (James S. Amelang & Siegfried Beer, eds.), at 161-165.
[12]   Lawrence Stone, Elizabethan Overseas Trade, 2 The Eco. Hist. Rev. 30 (New Series, 1949), at 37:
The main difference from the situation 200 years before was that cloth had now replaced wool as the staple English export. In this year cloth alone comprised 78% of the total value of all exports, and all types of wool, wool-fells and clothing amounted to over 90%. … For all intents and purposes England exported clothing and clothing materials and nothing else.
[13]   Id. at 39.
[14]   Charles Mathew Clode, The Early History of the Guild of Merchant Taylors of the Fraternity of St. John the Baptist, London 78 (1888) (“From early times the foreign workmen pressed very heavily upon the native craftsmen, taking work from them and keeping down the price of wages.”).
[15]   Derek Wilson, Evil May Day 1517, 67 History Today 68 (2017) (the riot was likely sparked by an Easter sermon that demonized foreigners for depriving English natives of wealth). The rioters were mostly poor laborers, watermen, or journeymen apprentices in tanning and brewing companies.
[16]   Id. at 69, explaining that customs duties made up the largest part of the king’s ordinary income. The Tudor regime, therefore, had no interest in inhibiting trade by restrictive practices. Id. Henry VIII and Wolsey had other methods of extracting much-needed cash from the foreigners to fund the king’s early military adventures and heavy personal expenditure. Id.
[17]   Graham Noble, “Evil May Day”: Re-Examining the Race Riot of 1517, 2008 History Rev. 37 (Sep’t. 2008), at 39.
[18]   Luu, supra note 176, at 1 at xxiii.
[19]   Letters of Denization and Acts of Naturalization for Aliens in England 1509-1603 (1893), vii.
[20]   Lien Bich Luu, Migration and Change: Religious Refugees and the London Economy, 1550-1600, 8 Critical Survey 93 (1996), at 98 (as economic conditions, worsened in the late 1500s attacks on foreigners peaked). In 1573, foreigners sought protection from London officials, complaining that they “‘have been of late molested and euell entreted going into the strete about there busines, by servants and apprentices undiscretly and without order whereof hurt may ensue (quoted in original text).’” Id.
[21]   32 Hen. 8, c. 16, § 1 (1540) (Eng.).
[22]   Sir Francis Bacon, Three Speeches of the Right Honorable 19 (1641).
[23]   Stone, supra note 184, at 45 (1949).

No comments: